by Dean Baker
Tim Congdon covers a lot of ground in his essay on Keynes, Krugman, and the liquidity trap. I will narrow my focus to the current crisis and the relevance of Keynes to the policies being pursued.
First, it is important to focus on an issue where there should really
be no grounds for disagreement: the size of the stimulus and its
expected impact. Contrary to what Congdon states in his piece, the
stimulus was closer to $300 billion a year (@ 2 percent of GDP) in 2009
and 2010, not $800 billion a year. The total stimulus package came in at
close to $800 billion. Nearly $100 billion involved a technical fix to
the alternative minimum tax, which is done every year and has nothing to
do with stimulus. Approximately $100 billion was slated to be spent
after 2010 in longer term projects. This leaves $600 billion, or roughly $300 billion to be spent in both calendar years, 2009 and 2010.
The expected impact of the stimulus can be determined by reading what
the Obama administration was saying about it at the time. The
projections in the paper by Christina Romer and Jared Bernstein, which
outlined the original proposal, showed that they expected it to create just 3.7 million jobs.
The package that they got through Congress was smaller and less
oriented toward spending than their original proposal, so the number of
jobs projected would have to be adjusted downward accordingly.
Finally, there is reason to believe that we did get roughly the number of jobs projected. James Feyrer and Bruce Sacerdote found in-state job multipliers that were comparable,
albeit slightly smaller, than the national multipliers assumed by Romer
and Bernstein. This is very positive from the standpoint of the success
of the stimulus, since national multipliers will always be higher than
in-state multipliers Many of the jobs created by spending in the state
of Delaware will be in New Jersey or Pennsylvania, so if anything the
Feyrer and Sacerdote paper suggests that the impact of the stimulus
might have been somewhat larger than had been expected.
The big failing of the Obama administration was not in their stimulus
package, but rather in their projections for the economy. Their
baseline assumed that unemployment would peak at around 9 percent in the
absence of the stimulus. Unemployment had already crossed this level at
9.4 percent in May, just as the first stimulus dollars were going out
the door, and we were still losing more than 400,000 jobs a month. The
administration had badly underestimated the severity of the downturn. In
effect, they had gotten a stimulus package through Congress that was
designed to create 3 million jobs in an economy that needed 10–12
million jobs.
Turning to Congdon’s theoretical points, he has seriously
misrepresented my friend Paul Krugman’s position. Krugman has argued
that conventional monetary policy, in the form of reducing the federal
funds rate, has reached its limits. That seems uncontroversial; the
federal funds rate is at zero and can’t go negative. However he has
repeatedly pushed for the use of unorthodox forms of monetary policy,
most notably targeting higher rates of inflation.
Krugman first wrote about the idea of targeting a higher rate of inflation in 1998,
in reference to the slump in Japan. He has repeated this suggestion in
reference to the current situation numerous times, both in his column
and blog and in academic work.
The logic is straightforward. In the current downturn we would like
to see much lower real interest rates. This is true for both the
short-term rate, which is already at its nominal floor, and also the
longer term rates that are more important for investment decisions. The
latter are largely subject to the sort of liquidity trap conditions that
Keynes described and Congdon references. The nominal long-term rate is
unlikely to fall further because bondholders do not want to take the
risk of capital losses.
In a situation where nominal interest rates have hit a floor, the
only way that the Fed can reduce the real interest rate is if can
credibly commit itself to sustaining a higher inflation rate. In
addition to encouraging investment by lowering real interest rates, a
higher inflation rate would also have the effect of reducing the debt
burden that is weighing down tens of millions of households. That should
have the effect of boosting consumption since heavily indebted
households are likely to have a higher propensity to consume out of
wealth than those who own the debt.
So contrary to Congdon’s contention, Krugman has been a vocal
advocate of monetary policy. Of course this is a different monetary
policy that Congdon’s suggestion that the Fed target M3. The level of M3
is not directly a policy variable under the control of the Fed. At a
time when banks hold excess reserves of more than $1.6 trillion, it
might be very difficult for the Fed to easily reach any target for
either M2 or M3. And, since there are well-known definitional problems
with both aggregates (which caused Milton Friedman to abandon his
commitment to monetary targeting toward the end of his life), I am
inclined to agree with Krugman’s policy over Congdon’s.
Of course, unlike Congdon, Krugman has also argued for fiscal policy,
in addition to pushing for a lower valued dollar to boost net exports.
The logic is that the government should be doing everything in its power
at this point to restore the economy to full employment.
Many of the workers and their families who are suffering through
spells of long-term unemployment are not going to recover from this
trauma. The prospects for being rehired after an extended period of
unemployment are poor, and the likelihood of finding a job that pays
close to the same as the prior job after an unemployment spell of one to
two years is extremely low.
Families who have seen their primary breadwinner laid off will be
struggling to make ends meet, especially if the period of unemployment
exceeds the period of benefit duration, which is increasingly common.
Many will risk losing their home or apartment. Long spells of
unemployment are often associated with family breakups and create an
unstable environment for children in school.
The unemployed workers are not the ones whose mismanagement led to
this economic crisis. Those in positions of authority have the
responsibility to protect them from a disaster that is not their fault.
In this context, Krugman and other Keynesians have argued for both
fiscal and monetary policy to get the economy back toward full
employment as quickly as possible. It is hard to see an economically or
morally justifiable alternative position.
No comments:
Post a Comment