The super-committee of Congress is the latest group to confess abject
defeat by the Treasury budget deficit. Who can be surprised by this
total failure? During the past generation Congress has made as many as
fifteen legislative attempts to control government spending — aimed
ultimately at a balanced budget. The most notable efforts were those
sponsored by the all-time budget hawk, Senator Phil Gramm of Texas. But
every administrative and legislative effort by the authorities, no
matter how well-intentioned, has collapsed. Why is this so?
Nobel economist Milton Friedman believed the solution to the budget
deficit problem was to deny Congress tax revenues. So he advised
Congressmen and Presidents to oppose all tax increases — thereby denying
bloated government the funds with which to increase spending. But
Friedman’s advice has failed, too. We know this because marginal tax
rates have been reduced from as high as 70% in 1964 to 15-20-39% in 2011
— depending on the type of income. But congressional spending has
nevertheless increased every year — such that, today, only 60% of the
Federal budget is financed by taxes, the remainder by Treasury debt.
Total direct Federal debt is now about equal to total U.S. output.
The intractable budget deficit and the inexorable rise of government
spending has a simpler explanation. Congress and the Treasury are in
possession of several open-ended charge accounts — “permanent credit
card financing” — with no limits. With its charge cards the Treasury can
borrow new credit (money) from the banking system — much of what it
needs every year to finance the ever-rising budget deficit.
A look at the current Federal Reserve Balance Sheet shows that the Fed has created about $1.7 trillion of new credit
(money) with which to purchase Treasury debt. Foreign central banks
have created about $2.7 trillion of new credit to purchase U.S. Treasury
bonds. This global, electronic, money-printing exercise has financed
almost 30% of the total direct debt of the U.S. Treasury. In 2002, Ben
Bernanke, now Chairman of the Fed, did not mince words to describe this
process: “[U]nder a fiat (that is, paper) money system, a government (in
practice, the central bank in cooperation with other agencies) should
always be able to generate increased nominal spending and inflation,
even when the short-term nominal interest rate is at zero…. [T]he U.S.
government has a technology, called a printing press (or, today, its
electronic equivalent), that allows it to produce as many U.S. dollars
as it wishes at essentially no cost.”
He might have added that these “no cost” dollars, printed by the Fed, are the enablers of the perennial U.S. budget deficit.
But the Fed is not the only credit card used by the Treasury to
finance the budget deficit. Because the dollar is the world’s reserve
currency, foreign central banks also finance U.S. budget deficits (as
the custody account of the Fed balance sheet shows). Domestic and
foreign commercial banks, too, supply vast amounts of new credit to the
U.S. Treasury because domestic, foreign, and international bank
regulators, such as the Basel authorities, define U.S. sovereign bonds
as high quality assets for which bank reserves are not necessary.
Therefore financial institutions can qualify their overleveraged balance
sheets by loading up on Treasury Securities. Indeed, only 10-20% of the
total direct debt of the U.S. Treasury is now owned by the non-bank,
non-government private market. In a word, given the reserve currency
role of the dollar, the Federal Reserve and foreign central banks have
been given every institutional incentive to finance the U.S. budget
deficit. Beginning with World War I, every monetary discipline has been
removed by domestic and international authorities, such that runaway
government spending everywhere relies on the ultimate credit card —
newly created money in the banking system.
The simplest solution to the government spending problem in Congress
is “to tear up” its credit cards. The way to do this is not with ad hoc
and unavailing administrative patchworks, all of which are nullified by
world banking system credit made available to the U.S. Treasury.
Instead, the effective democratic solution is authorized by the U.S.
Constitution — in Article I, Sections 8 and 10: — whereby the control of
the supply of dollars is entrusted to the hands of the people — where
it stayed for most of American history, especially from 1792 to 1914.
This was America’s longest period of rapid, non-inflationary, economic
growth — almost 4% annually, with the budget under control except
wartime.
Congress need only mobilize its unique, Article I, constitutional
power “to coin money and regulate the value thereof.” From 1792 to 1971
Congress defined by law the gold value of the currency such that paper
dollars and bank demand deposits were convertible to their gold
equivalent — by the people (1792-1914) and/or by governments
(1933-1971). Congress should exercise this constitutional power to
restore dollar-gold convertibility, because of the proven budgetary and
economic growth benefits of a dollar as good as gold.
First, the discipline of convertibility would automatically
set the limit on Treasury access to its Federal Reserve credit card. If
the Federal Reserve created more money than participants in the market
wanted to hold, people would get rid of the inflationary excess by
promptly exchanging paper and credit money for the gold equivalent. But
under the true gold standard, the Fed and the commercial banks would be
required by law to maintain dollar-gold convertibility at the statutory
gold-dollar parity — or suffer insolvency. In order to maintain dollar
convertibility to gold, the Fed and the commercial banks must reduce the
quantity of money and credit, including credit to the Treasury — thus
controlling government spending increases and inflation.
Second, the empirical evidence of American economic history
also shows that convertibility to gold stabilizes the value of the
dollar. The same evidence shows that a stable dollar also stabilizes the
general price level over the long run. For example, under the gold
standard, the price level in 1914 was at almost exactly the same level
as it was in 1879 and in 1834. There was no long term inflation, even
over an 80 year period! But from 1971 — Nixon’s termination of
dollar-gold convertibility — until 2011, the purchasing power of the
dollar (adjusted by the CPI) has fallen 85% in a 40 year period.
Third, gold convertibility of the dollar leads to a vast
outpouring of savings from inflation hedges such as commodities,
farmland, art, antiques — almost anything perceived to be a better store
of value than depreciating paper currencies. Stable money also creates
incentives to save from income. Combined with the global release of
trillions of hoarded, inert, unproductive inflation hedges,
convertibility triggers new savings which would pour into the productive
investment market. The new investment would give rise to a general
economic expansion — through new business, new products, new plant and
equipment, creating thereby a renewed demand for labor to work the
expanding production facilities.
The restoration of a dollar worth its weight in gold provides not
only a missing and necessary brake on government spending, but a stable
dollar supplies the missing steering wheel by which to guide the
immense, hoarded savings into long-term productive investment. Dollar
convertibility to gold is the simple, institutional financial reform
which terminates the fear of rapid inflation — thus transforming
unproductive, store-of-value hedges into real investment capital with
which to inaugurate a new American era of rapid economic and employment
growth.
No comments:
Post a Comment